Sunday , December 22 2024
Home / SNB & CHF / Minsky Meltdowns and Modern Monetary Theory

Minsky Meltdowns and Modern Monetary Theory

Summary:
Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) posits that booms and busts can be explained by private versus public sectoral balances and the inherent instability of private financial markets. Stephanie Kelton frequently points to this graph of public and private surpluses and deficits:The red bars show the government’s budget as a percent of GDP. When the government spends more than it collects in taxes, it runs a deficit and sells debt. The government’s debt is sold domestically and to foreign buyers. These groups become net lenders to the government to the extent they purchase government debt, and this is shown with the black and gray bars.When the government (rarely) runs a surplus, it means that the government is collecting more in taxes than it is spending, and so the

Topics:
Jonathan Newman considers the following as important: , ,

This could be interesting, too:

Nachrichten Ticker - www.finanzen.ch writes Krypto-Ausblick 2025: Stehen Bitcoin, Ethereum & Co. vor einem Boom oder Einbruch?

Connor O'Keeffe writes The Establishment’s “Principles” Are Fake

Per Bylund writes Bitcoiners’ Guide to Austrian Economics

Ron Paul writes What Are We Doing in Syria?

Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) posits that booms and busts can be explained by private versus public sectoral balances and the inherent instability of private financial markets. Stephanie Kelton frequently points to this graph of public and private surpluses and deficits:

Minsky Meltdowns and Modern Monetary Theory

The red bars show the government’s budget as a percent of GDP. When the government spends more than it collects in taxes, it runs a deficit and sells debt. The government’s debt is sold domestically and to foreign buyers. These groups become net lenders to the government to the extent they purchase government debt, and this is shown with the black and gray bars.

When the government (rarely) runs a surplus, it means that the government is collecting more in taxes than it is spending, and so the non-government sectors must collectively run a “deficit.”

This picture is highly misleading, as Bob Murphy and others have pointed out. Since interest payments from the federal government must come from either taxes or monetary inflation, the burden of government debt is not borne by the government, but by taxpayers and all the losers of money printing. Government deficits, then, are not really private sector surpluses, no matter how many times MMTers point at the sectoral balances.

Moreover, Kelton asserts that private sector deficits or a deterioration of private sector balance sheets are caused by government surpluses or smaller government deficits. Here, she takes a step beyond the mere accounting, which we’ve already seen is misleading, and makes a cause-and-effect claim. She says, “Government deficits are necessary to prevent private sector balance sheets from deteriorating.”

The problem with this is that government deficits are determined by two things: government spending and government revenues. Kelton implies that if only the government would increase spending to deepen deficits, then the private sector could stay afloat and we wouldn’t suffer downturns. But if you look at the time periods between recessions, the main driver of the changes in government deficits is tax revenues, which are a function of employment.

Minsky Meltdowns and Modern Monetary Theory

Source: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/graph/?g=1x3a9

Anybody familiar with Austrian business cycle will see what I’m getting at here. In the course of an unsustainable boom set in motion by artificially low interest rates, wages and employment increase, which means income tax revenues also increase. Higher tax revenues result in smaller government deficits and, in rare cases, government surpluses. Kelton claims that smaller government deficits lead to financial crises and recessions, but both are caused by credit expansion—first, government deficits shrink due to higher tax revenues, and then the inevitable bust, which is not caused by government deficits, but by the realization of errors made during the boom.

In the bust, government deficits get worse as government spending increases and tax revenues fall. This sets the stage for another time period between recessions for government spending to fall (but not back to pre-crisis levels), and for tax revenues to grow slowly as employment picks back up.

This is why there is an apparent correlation in government deficits and the business cycle. An uninformed observer could easily, but incorrectly, conclude causation from this correlation, saying that shrinking government deficits cause financial crises and recessions. In reality, artificial credit expansions cause both.

Kelton mentions Hyman Minsky, who developed a theory of financial crises based on the inherent instability of unregulated financial markets. The idea is that profits lead to speculative bubbles and overleveraging, and that this inevitably results in a default crisis. Households, businesses, and investors extrapolate the good times into the future, leading them to decrease savings, gamble their money in financial markets, and borrow more than they can pay back. As Janet Yellen put it in her speech at the 18th Annual Hyman P. Minsky Conference, “One of the critical features of Minsky’s world view is that borrowers, lenders, and regulators are lulled into complacency as asset prices rise. … a sense of safety on the part of investors is characteristic of financial booms.”

This, of course, is only part of the story. What enables such risky investment? What encourages excessive borrowing? What keeps interest rates low, even while there is a frenzy to borrow? How do profits, wages, asset prices, employment, stock market valuations, and debt all increase at the same time?

There’s a clue in Yellen’s speech, just a few moments later: “Fed monetary policy may also have contributed to the U.S. credit boom and the associated house price bubble by maintaining a highly accommodative stance from 2002 to 2004.”


Tags: ,

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *